Volatility in an at-the-money call option
$begingroup$
I understand that the vega of the Black-Scholes equation is a positive function, which means the value of the option is an INCREASING function of the volatility, since vega is the derivative of the value with respect to the volatility $sigma$.
On the other hand it is also true that for an at-the-money call option, the probability of exercise is a DECREASING function of $sigma$ since so is N(d2).
My question is: how can these two statements be true at the same time?
stochastic-calculus finance stochastic-pde
$endgroup$
add a comment |
$begingroup$
I understand that the vega of the Black-Scholes equation is a positive function, which means the value of the option is an INCREASING function of the volatility, since vega is the derivative of the value with respect to the volatility $sigma$.
On the other hand it is also true that for an at-the-money call option, the probability of exercise is a DECREASING function of $sigma$ since so is N(d2).
My question is: how can these two statements be true at the same time?
stochastic-calculus finance stochastic-pde
$endgroup$
$begingroup$
$Delta$ is the derivative with respect to the underlying, not volatility.
$endgroup$
– lulu
Feb 1 at 13:13
$begingroup$
You're right, I meant vega not delta. I'll correct it.
$endgroup$
– Lor
Feb 1 at 13:15
$begingroup$
But with that correction, surely the confusion goes away, right? If the option were sure to be exercised it would have no time value.
$endgroup$
– lulu
Feb 1 at 13:16
add a comment |
$begingroup$
I understand that the vega of the Black-Scholes equation is a positive function, which means the value of the option is an INCREASING function of the volatility, since vega is the derivative of the value with respect to the volatility $sigma$.
On the other hand it is also true that for an at-the-money call option, the probability of exercise is a DECREASING function of $sigma$ since so is N(d2).
My question is: how can these two statements be true at the same time?
stochastic-calculus finance stochastic-pde
$endgroup$
I understand that the vega of the Black-Scholes equation is a positive function, which means the value of the option is an INCREASING function of the volatility, since vega is the derivative of the value with respect to the volatility $sigma$.
On the other hand it is also true that for an at-the-money call option, the probability of exercise is a DECREASING function of $sigma$ since so is N(d2).
My question is: how can these two statements be true at the same time?
stochastic-calculus finance stochastic-pde
stochastic-calculus finance stochastic-pde
edited Feb 1 at 13:19
Lor
asked Feb 1 at 12:49
LorLor
283
283
$begingroup$
$Delta$ is the derivative with respect to the underlying, not volatility.
$endgroup$
– lulu
Feb 1 at 13:13
$begingroup$
You're right, I meant vega not delta. I'll correct it.
$endgroup$
– Lor
Feb 1 at 13:15
$begingroup$
But with that correction, surely the confusion goes away, right? If the option were sure to be exercised it would have no time value.
$endgroup$
– lulu
Feb 1 at 13:16
add a comment |
$begingroup$
$Delta$ is the derivative with respect to the underlying, not volatility.
$endgroup$
– lulu
Feb 1 at 13:13
$begingroup$
You're right, I meant vega not delta. I'll correct it.
$endgroup$
– Lor
Feb 1 at 13:15
$begingroup$
But with that correction, surely the confusion goes away, right? If the option were sure to be exercised it would have no time value.
$endgroup$
– lulu
Feb 1 at 13:16
$begingroup$
$Delta$ is the derivative with respect to the underlying, not volatility.
$endgroup$
– lulu
Feb 1 at 13:13
$begingroup$
$Delta$ is the derivative with respect to the underlying, not volatility.
$endgroup$
– lulu
Feb 1 at 13:13
$begingroup$
You're right, I meant vega not delta. I'll correct it.
$endgroup$
– Lor
Feb 1 at 13:15
$begingroup$
You're right, I meant vega not delta. I'll correct it.
$endgroup$
– Lor
Feb 1 at 13:15
$begingroup$
But with that correction, surely the confusion goes away, right? If the option were sure to be exercised it would have no time value.
$endgroup$
– lulu
Feb 1 at 13:16
$begingroup$
But with that correction, surely the confusion goes away, right? If the option were sure to be exercised it would have no time value.
$endgroup$
– lulu
Feb 1 at 13:16
add a comment |
1 Answer
1
active
oldest
votes
$begingroup$
This is a very astute observation and good question which reveals a seemingly paradoxical (and commonly known) aspect of the Black-Scholes model.
In the Black-Scholes model, the underlying asset price $S_t$ follows a geometric Brownian motion. Under the risk-neutral probability measure, we have at the time of option expiration, $T$, (where the dividend yield is WLOG assumed to be $0$)
$$S_T = S_0e^{(r- frac{sigma^2}{2})T}e^{sigmasqrt{T}xi},$$
where $r$ is the risk-free rate, $sigma$ is the volatility, and $xi sim N(0,1)$ is a standard normal random variable. Thus, $S_T$ has a lognormal distribution.
For a given strike price $K$, the risk-neutral probability that a call option expires in the money is
$$P(S_T > K) = P(log S_T > log K) = P(xi > -d_2), \ d_2 = frac{log frac{S_0e^{rT}}{K}}{sigma sqrt{T}} - frac{1}{2}sigmasqrt{T}$$
By the symmetry of the normal distribution, we have $P(xi > -d_2) = P(xi < d_2) = N(d_2)$. Now $d_2$ is decreasing for an at-the-money-forward option with respect to $sigma$. It is also eventually decreasing for any strike price. This confirms that the probability of exercise for a call option is $N(d_2)$ and is or eventually is decreasing with respect to volatility.
On the other hand, you are correct that vega is always positive and, therefore, the value of an option (call or put) must increase as the volatility is increased. This corresponds to the fact that the expected value of the payoff $mathbb{E}(max(S_T-K,0))$ increases as $sigma$ is increased for a lognormal distribution.
It would appear that we have a paradox, but the two facts are not inconsistent.
When the underlying price $S_T$ has a lognormal distribution, it is a nonnegative random variable, i.e. $P(S_T > 0) = 1$. As the volatility increases, the dispersion of the distribution increases and more probability mass accumulates in the finite interval $[0,K]$ than in the unbounded interval $[K,infty)$.
Now the Black-Scholes value of the call option without discounting is
$$e^{rT}V = S_0 N(d_2 + sigmasqrt{T}) - K N(d_2)$$
If the option expires in the money, then the holder in effect pays the strike price and takes delivery of the underlying asset. The strike price is fixed, but conditional on exercise the underlying asset that is delivered has unlimited upside potential. The second term is simply the expected value of the payment. Since this is $0$ if $S_T leqslant K$ and a constant $-K$ if $S_T > K$, this takes the form $-KN(d_2)$ and this will move closer to $0$ with increasing volatility since it is more likely it will not be realized. On the other hand, the first term always has a positive value and can be explained as
$$S_0N(d_2 + sigmasqrt{T}) = S_0frac{N(d_2 + sigmasqrt{T})}{N(d_2)} N(d_2) \ = mathbb{E}left[S_T |S_T> K right]P(S_T > K).$$
This term increases with $sigma$ because even though the probability of exercise decreases, the conditional expectation of the underlying asset price (with unlimited upside) increases at faster rate. The net effect of the behavior of both terms is, of course, that the value of the call option increases as the volatility is increased.
$endgroup$
add a comment |
Your Answer
StackExchange.ifUsing("editor", function () {
return StackExchange.using("mathjaxEditing", function () {
StackExchange.MarkdownEditor.creationCallbacks.add(function (editor, postfix) {
StackExchange.mathjaxEditing.prepareWmdForMathJax(editor, postfix, [["$", "$"], ["\\(","\\)"]]);
});
});
}, "mathjax-editing");
StackExchange.ready(function() {
var channelOptions = {
tags: "".split(" "),
id: "69"
};
initTagRenderer("".split(" "), "".split(" "), channelOptions);
StackExchange.using("externalEditor", function() {
// Have to fire editor after snippets, if snippets enabled
if (StackExchange.settings.snippets.snippetsEnabled) {
StackExchange.using("snippets", function() {
createEditor();
});
}
else {
createEditor();
}
});
function createEditor() {
StackExchange.prepareEditor({
heartbeatType: 'answer',
autoActivateHeartbeat: false,
convertImagesToLinks: true,
noModals: true,
showLowRepImageUploadWarning: true,
reputationToPostImages: 10,
bindNavPrevention: true,
postfix: "",
imageUploader: {
brandingHtml: "Powered by u003ca class="icon-imgur-white" href="https://imgur.com/"u003eu003c/au003e",
contentPolicyHtml: "User contributions licensed under u003ca href="https://creativecommons.org/licenses/by-sa/3.0/"u003ecc by-sa 3.0 with attribution requiredu003c/au003e u003ca href="https://stackoverflow.com/legal/content-policy"u003e(content policy)u003c/au003e",
allowUrls: true
},
noCode: true, onDemand: true,
discardSelector: ".discard-answer"
,immediatelyShowMarkdownHelp:true
});
}
});
Sign up or log in
StackExchange.ready(function () {
StackExchange.helpers.onClickDraftSave('#login-link');
});
Sign up using Google
Sign up using Facebook
Sign up using Email and Password
Post as a guest
Required, but never shown
StackExchange.ready(
function () {
StackExchange.openid.initPostLogin('.new-post-login', 'https%3a%2f%2fmath.stackexchange.com%2fquestions%2f3096189%2fvolatility-in-an-at-the-money-call-option%23new-answer', 'question_page');
}
);
Post as a guest
Required, but never shown
1 Answer
1
active
oldest
votes
1 Answer
1
active
oldest
votes
active
oldest
votes
active
oldest
votes
$begingroup$
This is a very astute observation and good question which reveals a seemingly paradoxical (and commonly known) aspect of the Black-Scholes model.
In the Black-Scholes model, the underlying asset price $S_t$ follows a geometric Brownian motion. Under the risk-neutral probability measure, we have at the time of option expiration, $T$, (where the dividend yield is WLOG assumed to be $0$)
$$S_T = S_0e^{(r- frac{sigma^2}{2})T}e^{sigmasqrt{T}xi},$$
where $r$ is the risk-free rate, $sigma$ is the volatility, and $xi sim N(0,1)$ is a standard normal random variable. Thus, $S_T$ has a lognormal distribution.
For a given strike price $K$, the risk-neutral probability that a call option expires in the money is
$$P(S_T > K) = P(log S_T > log K) = P(xi > -d_2), \ d_2 = frac{log frac{S_0e^{rT}}{K}}{sigma sqrt{T}} - frac{1}{2}sigmasqrt{T}$$
By the symmetry of the normal distribution, we have $P(xi > -d_2) = P(xi < d_2) = N(d_2)$. Now $d_2$ is decreasing for an at-the-money-forward option with respect to $sigma$. It is also eventually decreasing for any strike price. This confirms that the probability of exercise for a call option is $N(d_2)$ and is or eventually is decreasing with respect to volatility.
On the other hand, you are correct that vega is always positive and, therefore, the value of an option (call or put) must increase as the volatility is increased. This corresponds to the fact that the expected value of the payoff $mathbb{E}(max(S_T-K,0))$ increases as $sigma$ is increased for a lognormal distribution.
It would appear that we have a paradox, but the two facts are not inconsistent.
When the underlying price $S_T$ has a lognormal distribution, it is a nonnegative random variable, i.e. $P(S_T > 0) = 1$. As the volatility increases, the dispersion of the distribution increases and more probability mass accumulates in the finite interval $[0,K]$ than in the unbounded interval $[K,infty)$.
Now the Black-Scholes value of the call option without discounting is
$$e^{rT}V = S_0 N(d_2 + sigmasqrt{T}) - K N(d_2)$$
If the option expires in the money, then the holder in effect pays the strike price and takes delivery of the underlying asset. The strike price is fixed, but conditional on exercise the underlying asset that is delivered has unlimited upside potential. The second term is simply the expected value of the payment. Since this is $0$ if $S_T leqslant K$ and a constant $-K$ if $S_T > K$, this takes the form $-KN(d_2)$ and this will move closer to $0$ with increasing volatility since it is more likely it will not be realized. On the other hand, the first term always has a positive value and can be explained as
$$S_0N(d_2 + sigmasqrt{T}) = S_0frac{N(d_2 + sigmasqrt{T})}{N(d_2)} N(d_2) \ = mathbb{E}left[S_T |S_T> K right]P(S_T > K).$$
This term increases with $sigma$ because even though the probability of exercise decreases, the conditional expectation of the underlying asset price (with unlimited upside) increases at faster rate. The net effect of the behavior of both terms is, of course, that the value of the call option increases as the volatility is increased.
$endgroup$
add a comment |
$begingroup$
This is a very astute observation and good question which reveals a seemingly paradoxical (and commonly known) aspect of the Black-Scholes model.
In the Black-Scholes model, the underlying asset price $S_t$ follows a geometric Brownian motion. Under the risk-neutral probability measure, we have at the time of option expiration, $T$, (where the dividend yield is WLOG assumed to be $0$)
$$S_T = S_0e^{(r- frac{sigma^2}{2})T}e^{sigmasqrt{T}xi},$$
where $r$ is the risk-free rate, $sigma$ is the volatility, and $xi sim N(0,1)$ is a standard normal random variable. Thus, $S_T$ has a lognormal distribution.
For a given strike price $K$, the risk-neutral probability that a call option expires in the money is
$$P(S_T > K) = P(log S_T > log K) = P(xi > -d_2), \ d_2 = frac{log frac{S_0e^{rT}}{K}}{sigma sqrt{T}} - frac{1}{2}sigmasqrt{T}$$
By the symmetry of the normal distribution, we have $P(xi > -d_2) = P(xi < d_2) = N(d_2)$. Now $d_2$ is decreasing for an at-the-money-forward option with respect to $sigma$. It is also eventually decreasing for any strike price. This confirms that the probability of exercise for a call option is $N(d_2)$ and is or eventually is decreasing with respect to volatility.
On the other hand, you are correct that vega is always positive and, therefore, the value of an option (call or put) must increase as the volatility is increased. This corresponds to the fact that the expected value of the payoff $mathbb{E}(max(S_T-K,0))$ increases as $sigma$ is increased for a lognormal distribution.
It would appear that we have a paradox, but the two facts are not inconsistent.
When the underlying price $S_T$ has a lognormal distribution, it is a nonnegative random variable, i.e. $P(S_T > 0) = 1$. As the volatility increases, the dispersion of the distribution increases and more probability mass accumulates in the finite interval $[0,K]$ than in the unbounded interval $[K,infty)$.
Now the Black-Scholes value of the call option without discounting is
$$e^{rT}V = S_0 N(d_2 + sigmasqrt{T}) - K N(d_2)$$
If the option expires in the money, then the holder in effect pays the strike price and takes delivery of the underlying asset. The strike price is fixed, but conditional on exercise the underlying asset that is delivered has unlimited upside potential. The second term is simply the expected value of the payment. Since this is $0$ if $S_T leqslant K$ and a constant $-K$ if $S_T > K$, this takes the form $-KN(d_2)$ and this will move closer to $0$ with increasing volatility since it is more likely it will not be realized. On the other hand, the first term always has a positive value and can be explained as
$$S_0N(d_2 + sigmasqrt{T}) = S_0frac{N(d_2 + sigmasqrt{T})}{N(d_2)} N(d_2) \ = mathbb{E}left[S_T |S_T> K right]P(S_T > K).$$
This term increases with $sigma$ because even though the probability of exercise decreases, the conditional expectation of the underlying asset price (with unlimited upside) increases at faster rate. The net effect of the behavior of both terms is, of course, that the value of the call option increases as the volatility is increased.
$endgroup$
add a comment |
$begingroup$
This is a very astute observation and good question which reveals a seemingly paradoxical (and commonly known) aspect of the Black-Scholes model.
In the Black-Scholes model, the underlying asset price $S_t$ follows a geometric Brownian motion. Under the risk-neutral probability measure, we have at the time of option expiration, $T$, (where the dividend yield is WLOG assumed to be $0$)
$$S_T = S_0e^{(r- frac{sigma^2}{2})T}e^{sigmasqrt{T}xi},$$
where $r$ is the risk-free rate, $sigma$ is the volatility, and $xi sim N(0,1)$ is a standard normal random variable. Thus, $S_T$ has a lognormal distribution.
For a given strike price $K$, the risk-neutral probability that a call option expires in the money is
$$P(S_T > K) = P(log S_T > log K) = P(xi > -d_2), \ d_2 = frac{log frac{S_0e^{rT}}{K}}{sigma sqrt{T}} - frac{1}{2}sigmasqrt{T}$$
By the symmetry of the normal distribution, we have $P(xi > -d_2) = P(xi < d_2) = N(d_2)$. Now $d_2$ is decreasing for an at-the-money-forward option with respect to $sigma$. It is also eventually decreasing for any strike price. This confirms that the probability of exercise for a call option is $N(d_2)$ and is or eventually is decreasing with respect to volatility.
On the other hand, you are correct that vega is always positive and, therefore, the value of an option (call or put) must increase as the volatility is increased. This corresponds to the fact that the expected value of the payoff $mathbb{E}(max(S_T-K,0))$ increases as $sigma$ is increased for a lognormal distribution.
It would appear that we have a paradox, but the two facts are not inconsistent.
When the underlying price $S_T$ has a lognormal distribution, it is a nonnegative random variable, i.e. $P(S_T > 0) = 1$. As the volatility increases, the dispersion of the distribution increases and more probability mass accumulates in the finite interval $[0,K]$ than in the unbounded interval $[K,infty)$.
Now the Black-Scholes value of the call option without discounting is
$$e^{rT}V = S_0 N(d_2 + sigmasqrt{T}) - K N(d_2)$$
If the option expires in the money, then the holder in effect pays the strike price and takes delivery of the underlying asset. The strike price is fixed, but conditional on exercise the underlying asset that is delivered has unlimited upside potential. The second term is simply the expected value of the payment. Since this is $0$ if $S_T leqslant K$ and a constant $-K$ if $S_T > K$, this takes the form $-KN(d_2)$ and this will move closer to $0$ with increasing volatility since it is more likely it will not be realized. On the other hand, the first term always has a positive value and can be explained as
$$S_0N(d_2 + sigmasqrt{T}) = S_0frac{N(d_2 + sigmasqrt{T})}{N(d_2)} N(d_2) \ = mathbb{E}left[S_T |S_T> K right]P(S_T > K).$$
This term increases with $sigma$ because even though the probability of exercise decreases, the conditional expectation of the underlying asset price (with unlimited upside) increases at faster rate. The net effect of the behavior of both terms is, of course, that the value of the call option increases as the volatility is increased.
$endgroup$
This is a very astute observation and good question which reveals a seemingly paradoxical (and commonly known) aspect of the Black-Scholes model.
In the Black-Scholes model, the underlying asset price $S_t$ follows a geometric Brownian motion. Under the risk-neutral probability measure, we have at the time of option expiration, $T$, (where the dividend yield is WLOG assumed to be $0$)
$$S_T = S_0e^{(r- frac{sigma^2}{2})T}e^{sigmasqrt{T}xi},$$
where $r$ is the risk-free rate, $sigma$ is the volatility, and $xi sim N(0,1)$ is a standard normal random variable. Thus, $S_T$ has a lognormal distribution.
For a given strike price $K$, the risk-neutral probability that a call option expires in the money is
$$P(S_T > K) = P(log S_T > log K) = P(xi > -d_2), \ d_2 = frac{log frac{S_0e^{rT}}{K}}{sigma sqrt{T}} - frac{1}{2}sigmasqrt{T}$$
By the symmetry of the normal distribution, we have $P(xi > -d_2) = P(xi < d_2) = N(d_2)$. Now $d_2$ is decreasing for an at-the-money-forward option with respect to $sigma$. It is also eventually decreasing for any strike price. This confirms that the probability of exercise for a call option is $N(d_2)$ and is or eventually is decreasing with respect to volatility.
On the other hand, you are correct that vega is always positive and, therefore, the value of an option (call or put) must increase as the volatility is increased. This corresponds to the fact that the expected value of the payoff $mathbb{E}(max(S_T-K,0))$ increases as $sigma$ is increased for a lognormal distribution.
It would appear that we have a paradox, but the two facts are not inconsistent.
When the underlying price $S_T$ has a lognormal distribution, it is a nonnegative random variable, i.e. $P(S_T > 0) = 1$. As the volatility increases, the dispersion of the distribution increases and more probability mass accumulates in the finite interval $[0,K]$ than in the unbounded interval $[K,infty)$.
Now the Black-Scholes value of the call option without discounting is
$$e^{rT}V = S_0 N(d_2 + sigmasqrt{T}) - K N(d_2)$$
If the option expires in the money, then the holder in effect pays the strike price and takes delivery of the underlying asset. The strike price is fixed, but conditional on exercise the underlying asset that is delivered has unlimited upside potential. The second term is simply the expected value of the payment. Since this is $0$ if $S_T leqslant K$ and a constant $-K$ if $S_T > K$, this takes the form $-KN(d_2)$ and this will move closer to $0$ with increasing volatility since it is more likely it will not be realized. On the other hand, the first term always has a positive value and can be explained as
$$S_0N(d_2 + sigmasqrt{T}) = S_0frac{N(d_2 + sigmasqrt{T})}{N(d_2)} N(d_2) \ = mathbb{E}left[S_T |S_T> K right]P(S_T > K).$$
This term increases with $sigma$ because even though the probability of exercise decreases, the conditional expectation of the underlying asset price (with unlimited upside) increases at faster rate. The net effect of the behavior of both terms is, of course, that the value of the call option increases as the volatility is increased.
edited Feb 2 at 9:25
answered Feb 2 at 8:51
RRLRRL
53.5k52574
53.5k52574
add a comment |
add a comment |
Thanks for contributing an answer to Mathematics Stack Exchange!
- Please be sure to answer the question. Provide details and share your research!
But avoid …
- Asking for help, clarification, or responding to other answers.
- Making statements based on opinion; back them up with references or personal experience.
Use MathJax to format equations. MathJax reference.
To learn more, see our tips on writing great answers.
Sign up or log in
StackExchange.ready(function () {
StackExchange.helpers.onClickDraftSave('#login-link');
});
Sign up using Google
Sign up using Facebook
Sign up using Email and Password
Post as a guest
Required, but never shown
StackExchange.ready(
function () {
StackExchange.openid.initPostLogin('.new-post-login', 'https%3a%2f%2fmath.stackexchange.com%2fquestions%2f3096189%2fvolatility-in-an-at-the-money-call-option%23new-answer', 'question_page');
}
);
Post as a guest
Required, but never shown
Sign up or log in
StackExchange.ready(function () {
StackExchange.helpers.onClickDraftSave('#login-link');
});
Sign up using Google
Sign up using Facebook
Sign up using Email and Password
Post as a guest
Required, but never shown
Sign up or log in
StackExchange.ready(function () {
StackExchange.helpers.onClickDraftSave('#login-link');
});
Sign up using Google
Sign up using Facebook
Sign up using Email and Password
Post as a guest
Required, but never shown
Sign up or log in
StackExchange.ready(function () {
StackExchange.helpers.onClickDraftSave('#login-link');
});
Sign up using Google
Sign up using Facebook
Sign up using Email and Password
Sign up using Google
Sign up using Facebook
Sign up using Email and Password
Post as a guest
Required, but never shown
Required, but never shown
Required, but never shown
Required, but never shown
Required, but never shown
Required, but never shown
Required, but never shown
Required, but never shown
Required, but never shown
$begingroup$
$Delta$ is the derivative with respect to the underlying, not volatility.
$endgroup$
– lulu
Feb 1 at 13:13
$begingroup$
You're right, I meant vega not delta. I'll correct it.
$endgroup$
– Lor
Feb 1 at 13:15
$begingroup$
But with that correction, surely the confusion goes away, right? If the option were sure to be exercised it would have no time value.
$endgroup$
– lulu
Feb 1 at 13:16