what is the Nash equilibrium in a Third price auction?
Consider an auction in which the winner is the highest bidder, and he pays the third highest bid. Suppose there are three players and each player $iin{1,2,3}$ has a valuation $v_i$ and bids $b_i$. Without loss of generality, assume $v_1>v_2>v_3$. In case of a tie, the bidder with the lowest index $i$ wins and pays $min_{i}(b_i)$. The payoff of the winner $i$ is given by $v_i-p_i$, where $p_i$ is the value he will have to pay. The other bidders get a payoff of zero.
(a) Show that truth-telling (i.e. $b_i=v_i$ $forall i$) is in general not a Nash equilibrium of this auction.
For this I have said:
Truth telling is not a dominant strategy with this auction. In order to explain this I will need you to suppose that I value an item at $100, and there are 2 other bids, $200 and $10. I should bid $201 and pay only $10 for the item (note that the bid is higher than my private valuation).
Consider three bidders. Suppose bidders 1 and 2 submit bids , respectively, and bidder 3's value is such that . If bidder 3 bids truthfully, her payoff is 0, because bidder 2 will win the object. However, if bidder 3 overbids, so that , then she would win the auction and get a positive payoff This shows that truthful bidding is not a dominant strategy: there exists a situation where playing truthful bidding is not a best response.
In the third price auction, the expected utility of for the bidder is: ( is your own bid, is the bid of the third place.)
(b) Show that everyone bidding the highest valuation (i.e. $b_i=v_1$ $forall i$) is a Nash equilibrium of
this auction.
I have no idea how to answer this one... someone please help
game-theory nash-equilibrium auction-theory
add a comment |
Consider an auction in which the winner is the highest bidder, and he pays the third highest bid. Suppose there are three players and each player $iin{1,2,3}$ has a valuation $v_i$ and bids $b_i$. Without loss of generality, assume $v_1>v_2>v_3$. In case of a tie, the bidder with the lowest index $i$ wins and pays $min_{i}(b_i)$. The payoff of the winner $i$ is given by $v_i-p_i$, where $p_i$ is the value he will have to pay. The other bidders get a payoff of zero.
(a) Show that truth-telling (i.e. $b_i=v_i$ $forall i$) is in general not a Nash equilibrium of this auction.
For this I have said:
Truth telling is not a dominant strategy with this auction. In order to explain this I will need you to suppose that I value an item at $100, and there are 2 other bids, $200 and $10. I should bid $201 and pay only $10 for the item (note that the bid is higher than my private valuation).
Consider three bidders. Suppose bidders 1 and 2 submit bids , respectively, and bidder 3's value is such that . If bidder 3 bids truthfully, her payoff is 0, because bidder 2 will win the object. However, if bidder 3 overbids, so that , then she would win the auction and get a positive payoff This shows that truthful bidding is not a dominant strategy: there exists a situation where playing truthful bidding is not a best response.
In the third price auction, the expected utility of for the bidder is: ( is your own bid, is the bid of the third place.)
(b) Show that everyone bidding the highest valuation (i.e. $b_i=v_1$ $forall i$) is a Nash equilibrium of
this auction.
I have no idea how to answer this one... someone please help
game-theory nash-equilibrium auction-theory
add a comment |
Consider an auction in which the winner is the highest bidder, and he pays the third highest bid. Suppose there are three players and each player $iin{1,2,3}$ has a valuation $v_i$ and bids $b_i$. Without loss of generality, assume $v_1>v_2>v_3$. In case of a tie, the bidder with the lowest index $i$ wins and pays $min_{i}(b_i)$. The payoff of the winner $i$ is given by $v_i-p_i$, where $p_i$ is the value he will have to pay. The other bidders get a payoff of zero.
(a) Show that truth-telling (i.e. $b_i=v_i$ $forall i$) is in general not a Nash equilibrium of this auction.
For this I have said:
Truth telling is not a dominant strategy with this auction. In order to explain this I will need you to suppose that I value an item at $100, and there are 2 other bids, $200 and $10. I should bid $201 and pay only $10 for the item (note that the bid is higher than my private valuation).
Consider three bidders. Suppose bidders 1 and 2 submit bids , respectively, and bidder 3's value is such that . If bidder 3 bids truthfully, her payoff is 0, because bidder 2 will win the object. However, if bidder 3 overbids, so that , then she would win the auction and get a positive payoff This shows that truthful bidding is not a dominant strategy: there exists a situation where playing truthful bidding is not a best response.
In the third price auction, the expected utility of for the bidder is: ( is your own bid, is the bid of the third place.)
(b) Show that everyone bidding the highest valuation (i.e. $b_i=v_1$ $forall i$) is a Nash equilibrium of
this auction.
I have no idea how to answer this one... someone please help
game-theory nash-equilibrium auction-theory
Consider an auction in which the winner is the highest bidder, and he pays the third highest bid. Suppose there are three players and each player $iin{1,2,3}$ has a valuation $v_i$ and bids $b_i$. Without loss of generality, assume $v_1>v_2>v_3$. In case of a tie, the bidder with the lowest index $i$ wins and pays $min_{i}(b_i)$. The payoff of the winner $i$ is given by $v_i-p_i$, where $p_i$ is the value he will have to pay. The other bidders get a payoff of zero.
(a) Show that truth-telling (i.e. $b_i=v_i$ $forall i$) is in general not a Nash equilibrium of this auction.
For this I have said:
Truth telling is not a dominant strategy with this auction. In order to explain this I will need you to suppose that I value an item at $100, and there are 2 other bids, $200 and $10. I should bid $201 and pay only $10 for the item (note that the bid is higher than my private valuation).
Consider three bidders. Suppose bidders 1 and 2 submit bids , respectively, and bidder 3's value is such that . If bidder 3 bids truthfully, her payoff is 0, because bidder 2 will win the object. However, if bidder 3 overbids, so that , then she would win the auction and get a positive payoff This shows that truthful bidding is not a dominant strategy: there exists a situation where playing truthful bidding is not a best response.
In the third price auction, the expected utility of for the bidder is: ( is your own bid, is the bid of the third place.)
(b) Show that everyone bidding the highest valuation (i.e. $b_i=v_1$ $forall i$) is a Nash equilibrium of
this auction.
I have no idea how to answer this one... someone please help
game-theory nash-equilibrium auction-theory
game-theory nash-equilibrium auction-theory
edited Nov 21 '18 at 9:23
smcc
4,297517
4,297517
asked Nov 21 '18 at 1:00
Jose Luis Montalvo Ferreiro
61
61
add a comment |
add a comment |
1 Answer
1
active
oldest
votes
In (a) you are not asked whether bidding the valuation is a dominant strategy. Instead, you need to show that $(b_1,b_2,b_3)=(v_1,v_2,v_3)$ is not a Nash equilibrium. To do this, you just need to show that a player has a strictly profitable deviation. So, suppose $(b_1,b_2,b_3)=(v_1,v_2,v_3)$. Player 2's pay off is zero. If they increase their bid to something more than $v_1$, then they win the auction, pay the third highest bid $v_3$, and get a payoff of $v_2-v_3>0$. This is a strictly profitable deviation, so all players bidding their valuation is not a Nash equilibrium.
For (b), to show $(b_1,b_2,b_3)=(v_1,v_1,v_1)$ is a Nash equilibrium, you need to show that no player has a strictly profitable deviation from bidding $v_1$ (when the other players are bidding $v_1$). When players all bid $v_1$, they all get zero payoff (players 2 and 3 because they do not win the auction, and player 1 because they win the auction and pay $v_1$).
- If player 1 raises their bid, they still win the auction and pay $v_1$ and get zero payoff. If player 1 lowers their bid, they lose the auction and get zero payoff.
- If player 2 or 3 raise their bid, they win the auction and pay $v_1(>v_2>v_3)$ so make a loss. If player 2 or 3 lowers their bid, they lose the auction and get zero payoff.
Thus, no player has a strictly profitable deviation, and hence it is a Nash equilibrium for all players to bid the highest valuation $v_1$.
add a comment |
Your Answer
StackExchange.ifUsing("editor", function () {
return StackExchange.using("mathjaxEditing", function () {
StackExchange.MarkdownEditor.creationCallbacks.add(function (editor, postfix) {
StackExchange.mathjaxEditing.prepareWmdForMathJax(editor, postfix, [["$", "$"], ["\\(","\\)"]]);
});
});
}, "mathjax-editing");
StackExchange.ready(function() {
var channelOptions = {
tags: "".split(" "),
id: "69"
};
initTagRenderer("".split(" "), "".split(" "), channelOptions);
StackExchange.using("externalEditor", function() {
// Have to fire editor after snippets, if snippets enabled
if (StackExchange.settings.snippets.snippetsEnabled) {
StackExchange.using("snippets", function() {
createEditor();
});
}
else {
createEditor();
}
});
function createEditor() {
StackExchange.prepareEditor({
heartbeatType: 'answer',
autoActivateHeartbeat: false,
convertImagesToLinks: true,
noModals: true,
showLowRepImageUploadWarning: true,
reputationToPostImages: 10,
bindNavPrevention: true,
postfix: "",
imageUploader: {
brandingHtml: "Powered by u003ca class="icon-imgur-white" href="https://imgur.com/"u003eu003c/au003e",
contentPolicyHtml: "User contributions licensed under u003ca href="https://creativecommons.org/licenses/by-sa/3.0/"u003ecc by-sa 3.0 with attribution requiredu003c/au003e u003ca href="https://stackoverflow.com/legal/content-policy"u003e(content policy)u003c/au003e",
allowUrls: true
},
noCode: true, onDemand: true,
discardSelector: ".discard-answer"
,immediatelyShowMarkdownHelp:true
});
}
});
Sign up or log in
StackExchange.ready(function () {
StackExchange.helpers.onClickDraftSave('#login-link');
});
Sign up using Google
Sign up using Facebook
Sign up using Email and Password
Post as a guest
Required, but never shown
StackExchange.ready(
function () {
StackExchange.openid.initPostLogin('.new-post-login', 'https%3a%2f%2fmath.stackexchange.com%2fquestions%2f3007116%2fwhat-is-the-nash-equilibrium-in-a-third-price-auction%23new-answer', 'question_page');
}
);
Post as a guest
Required, but never shown
1 Answer
1
active
oldest
votes
1 Answer
1
active
oldest
votes
active
oldest
votes
active
oldest
votes
In (a) you are not asked whether bidding the valuation is a dominant strategy. Instead, you need to show that $(b_1,b_2,b_3)=(v_1,v_2,v_3)$ is not a Nash equilibrium. To do this, you just need to show that a player has a strictly profitable deviation. So, suppose $(b_1,b_2,b_3)=(v_1,v_2,v_3)$. Player 2's pay off is zero. If they increase their bid to something more than $v_1$, then they win the auction, pay the third highest bid $v_3$, and get a payoff of $v_2-v_3>0$. This is a strictly profitable deviation, so all players bidding their valuation is not a Nash equilibrium.
For (b), to show $(b_1,b_2,b_3)=(v_1,v_1,v_1)$ is a Nash equilibrium, you need to show that no player has a strictly profitable deviation from bidding $v_1$ (when the other players are bidding $v_1$). When players all bid $v_1$, they all get zero payoff (players 2 and 3 because they do not win the auction, and player 1 because they win the auction and pay $v_1$).
- If player 1 raises their bid, they still win the auction and pay $v_1$ and get zero payoff. If player 1 lowers their bid, they lose the auction and get zero payoff.
- If player 2 or 3 raise their bid, they win the auction and pay $v_1(>v_2>v_3)$ so make a loss. If player 2 or 3 lowers their bid, they lose the auction and get zero payoff.
Thus, no player has a strictly profitable deviation, and hence it is a Nash equilibrium for all players to bid the highest valuation $v_1$.
add a comment |
In (a) you are not asked whether bidding the valuation is a dominant strategy. Instead, you need to show that $(b_1,b_2,b_3)=(v_1,v_2,v_3)$ is not a Nash equilibrium. To do this, you just need to show that a player has a strictly profitable deviation. So, suppose $(b_1,b_2,b_3)=(v_1,v_2,v_3)$. Player 2's pay off is zero. If they increase their bid to something more than $v_1$, then they win the auction, pay the third highest bid $v_3$, and get a payoff of $v_2-v_3>0$. This is a strictly profitable deviation, so all players bidding their valuation is not a Nash equilibrium.
For (b), to show $(b_1,b_2,b_3)=(v_1,v_1,v_1)$ is a Nash equilibrium, you need to show that no player has a strictly profitable deviation from bidding $v_1$ (when the other players are bidding $v_1$). When players all bid $v_1$, they all get zero payoff (players 2 and 3 because they do not win the auction, and player 1 because they win the auction and pay $v_1$).
- If player 1 raises their bid, they still win the auction and pay $v_1$ and get zero payoff. If player 1 lowers their bid, they lose the auction and get zero payoff.
- If player 2 or 3 raise their bid, they win the auction and pay $v_1(>v_2>v_3)$ so make a loss. If player 2 or 3 lowers their bid, they lose the auction and get zero payoff.
Thus, no player has a strictly profitable deviation, and hence it is a Nash equilibrium for all players to bid the highest valuation $v_1$.
add a comment |
In (a) you are not asked whether bidding the valuation is a dominant strategy. Instead, you need to show that $(b_1,b_2,b_3)=(v_1,v_2,v_3)$ is not a Nash equilibrium. To do this, you just need to show that a player has a strictly profitable deviation. So, suppose $(b_1,b_2,b_3)=(v_1,v_2,v_3)$. Player 2's pay off is zero. If they increase their bid to something more than $v_1$, then they win the auction, pay the third highest bid $v_3$, and get a payoff of $v_2-v_3>0$. This is a strictly profitable deviation, so all players bidding their valuation is not a Nash equilibrium.
For (b), to show $(b_1,b_2,b_3)=(v_1,v_1,v_1)$ is a Nash equilibrium, you need to show that no player has a strictly profitable deviation from bidding $v_1$ (when the other players are bidding $v_1$). When players all bid $v_1$, they all get zero payoff (players 2 and 3 because they do not win the auction, and player 1 because they win the auction and pay $v_1$).
- If player 1 raises their bid, they still win the auction and pay $v_1$ and get zero payoff. If player 1 lowers their bid, they lose the auction and get zero payoff.
- If player 2 or 3 raise their bid, they win the auction and pay $v_1(>v_2>v_3)$ so make a loss. If player 2 or 3 lowers their bid, they lose the auction and get zero payoff.
Thus, no player has a strictly profitable deviation, and hence it is a Nash equilibrium for all players to bid the highest valuation $v_1$.
In (a) you are not asked whether bidding the valuation is a dominant strategy. Instead, you need to show that $(b_1,b_2,b_3)=(v_1,v_2,v_3)$ is not a Nash equilibrium. To do this, you just need to show that a player has a strictly profitable deviation. So, suppose $(b_1,b_2,b_3)=(v_1,v_2,v_3)$. Player 2's pay off is zero. If they increase their bid to something more than $v_1$, then they win the auction, pay the third highest bid $v_3$, and get a payoff of $v_2-v_3>0$. This is a strictly profitable deviation, so all players bidding their valuation is not a Nash equilibrium.
For (b), to show $(b_1,b_2,b_3)=(v_1,v_1,v_1)$ is a Nash equilibrium, you need to show that no player has a strictly profitable deviation from bidding $v_1$ (when the other players are bidding $v_1$). When players all bid $v_1$, they all get zero payoff (players 2 and 3 because they do not win the auction, and player 1 because they win the auction and pay $v_1$).
- If player 1 raises their bid, they still win the auction and pay $v_1$ and get zero payoff. If player 1 lowers their bid, they lose the auction and get zero payoff.
- If player 2 or 3 raise their bid, they win the auction and pay $v_1(>v_2>v_3)$ so make a loss. If player 2 or 3 lowers their bid, they lose the auction and get zero payoff.
Thus, no player has a strictly profitable deviation, and hence it is a Nash equilibrium for all players to bid the highest valuation $v_1$.
edited Nov 23 '18 at 7:45
answered Nov 21 '18 at 9:17
smcc
4,297517
4,297517
add a comment |
add a comment |
Thanks for contributing an answer to Mathematics Stack Exchange!
- Please be sure to answer the question. Provide details and share your research!
But avoid …
- Asking for help, clarification, or responding to other answers.
- Making statements based on opinion; back them up with references or personal experience.
Use MathJax to format equations. MathJax reference.
To learn more, see our tips on writing great answers.
Some of your past answers have not been well-received, and you're in danger of being blocked from answering.
Please pay close attention to the following guidance:
- Please be sure to answer the question. Provide details and share your research!
But avoid …
- Asking for help, clarification, or responding to other answers.
- Making statements based on opinion; back them up with references or personal experience.
To learn more, see our tips on writing great answers.
Sign up or log in
StackExchange.ready(function () {
StackExchange.helpers.onClickDraftSave('#login-link');
});
Sign up using Google
Sign up using Facebook
Sign up using Email and Password
Post as a guest
Required, but never shown
StackExchange.ready(
function () {
StackExchange.openid.initPostLogin('.new-post-login', 'https%3a%2f%2fmath.stackexchange.com%2fquestions%2f3007116%2fwhat-is-the-nash-equilibrium-in-a-third-price-auction%23new-answer', 'question_page');
}
);
Post as a guest
Required, but never shown
Sign up or log in
StackExchange.ready(function () {
StackExchange.helpers.onClickDraftSave('#login-link');
});
Sign up using Google
Sign up using Facebook
Sign up using Email and Password
Post as a guest
Required, but never shown
Sign up or log in
StackExchange.ready(function () {
StackExchange.helpers.onClickDraftSave('#login-link');
});
Sign up using Google
Sign up using Facebook
Sign up using Email and Password
Post as a guest
Required, but never shown
Sign up or log in
StackExchange.ready(function () {
StackExchange.helpers.onClickDraftSave('#login-link');
});
Sign up using Google
Sign up using Facebook
Sign up using Email and Password
Sign up using Google
Sign up using Facebook
Sign up using Email and Password
Post as a guest
Required, but never shown
Required, but never shown
Required, but never shown
Required, but never shown
Required, but never shown
Required, but never shown
Required, but never shown
Required, but never shown
Required, but never shown